Showing posts with label ECB. Show all posts
Showing posts with label ECB. Show all posts

Monday, April 4, 2016

A flash in the sky



65 million years ago, the dinosaurs ruled the earth. No other specie could compete in diversity, dominance nor offer surer prospects for more of the same for eons to come. And then, suddenly, they were gone. A catastrophic event, perhaps a large asteroid crashing into the sea off the coast of Yucatan. The world would never be the same after that.

For decades, macroeconomic management in western economies was carried out through the competing and complementary efforts of business practitioners (mostly ex-bankers) and economists. The final arbitrages were made by elected politicians.

This balance of influences served us well. “New” ideas were thoroughly debated between theoreticians and practitioners, with the most toxic ones being filtered out. This didn’t prevent preeminent economists like Paul Volcker or bankers like Robert Rubin from making key positive contributions to the economy.

But then came the financial crisis of 2008 and the ensuing Great Recession, and the banker specie became extinct, figuratively speaking.  (Investment) bankers
[1] had been playing with fire, resorting to dizzying debt leverage, funding huge quantities of dodgy mortgage loans with overnight funding, betting on derivatives without properly hedging themselves, and the list goes on.

In truth, bankers were not the only ones responsible for the crisis, but they were the richest, they were politically tone deaf and they were the ones standing among the ruins. Politicians were equally despised, but since they couldn't be fired, knew how to quickly blame somebody else, and fake compassion by writing new regulations and imposing huge fines on bank shareholders to atone for the sins of bank executives, they survived.

The economists were neither rich nor elected, and they had two hands (“on the one hand…on the other hand..”). And so the new era of the homo economicus began.

Unchecked, unchallenged, economists rose to the status of doers, saviors, and seers. They were empowered to carry out real life experiments on a massive scale and test their theories in the real world.

The last act of the banker/economist tandem (Paulson/Bernanke) of opening the liquidity spigot and forcing a massive recapitalization of the banking sector was appropriate at the time.

But subsequent and continuing experiments in printing huge amounts of money, forcing interest rates down to zero and even below, and in having central banks buy hundreds of billions of shaky sovereign and corporate bonds have hardly been conducive to inspiring confidence.

Under such altered financial states, home owners may see their equity go up (because of rock bottom capitalization rates), but they also see their investment income collapse to a trickle.  Not likely to encourage splurging.

Working people, if they pay attention, worry that their pension plans are way behind in building up the kind of retirement assets they will need later in life.  In all, some five trillion dollars in public and private US pension plans are affected.  It is even worse in Europe.

While governments have taken tens of trillions in new debt, they expect their national currencies to weaken just enough to facilitate exports but not enough to trigger capital flight.  Good luck with that.  And whose currency is appreciating to soak all these exports?

The current economists’ bold plans remind me of the Collor Plan in Brazil, back in the early 1990s.  One of its key measures to crush inflation was to drastically reduce demand by freezing financial assets.  All of a sudden, households couldn’t touch their investment accounts, could only withdraw US$600 from their savings accounts and up to 20% of their interest-bearing checking accounts!  That monetary freeze was to last six months!  And ultimately the frozen money would only have limited use.

Debasing the currency, targeting private savings, encouraging excessive risk taking may help balancing some equations on paper, but they destroy confidence, and without confidence there is no economic growth.

In fairness to economists, bickering politicians had left monetary policy as the avenue of last resort. But the adepts of the Dismal Science didn’t need much encouragement.

And now these sorcerer’s apprentices must undo their clever constructs, like Disney eponymous character.  I may be wrong, but the reign of the economists is unlikely to challenge that of the dinosaurs.




[1]  By and large, the most egregious excesses were committed b investment bankers, but some commercial bankers joined the fray.

Monday, December 3, 2012

21012 in review: Greece revisited


As the year comes to a close, I feel that it is healthy to revisit the posts written so far and to assess how events have tracked our expectations and predictions.  This is the first installment of the series.

It has been our view that Greece would not be able to fulfill its commitments to the rest of EU and that the adjustments it needed to make were so great that it should and would leave the eurozone, at least temporarily, if not this year at least next.  We have also felt that the single most effective tool at its disposal to correct excessive debt loads was privatization of public assets, which it has refused to implement: of some €300 billion in privatizable public assets[1], only €50 billion were earmarked for sale, and to-date, cash proceeds to the Greek government have been €1.8 billion only. 

So far, Greece remains in the eurozone despite having spectacularly failed meeting its targets and carrying unsustainable debt loads.  Last March, the Greek government agreed to a series of targets with the Troika (European Commission, ECB, IMF), such as bringing its debt-to-GDP ratio down to 120% by 2020; despite a severe “haircut” imposed on private creditors, that ratio stood at 150% by mid-year and was budgeted to rise to 189% by 2014.  Such huge “miss” was due to both a collapsing economy and rising debts.  The budget deficit target will be missed as well.  Further adjustments include more cuts in public sector salaries, pensions and other social transfers, and of course, better tax collection.

Faced with unattainable goals, the Troika decided to fudge, increasing the 2020 debt-to-GDP goal to 124%, reducing interest rates on loans to Greece, returning realized profits on previous ECB financial aid operations and requesting Greece to buy back debt[2] (at a discount) before disbursing the next aid package.

This next disbursement of €34.4 billion is not assured yet.  It is also huge as it represents 17% of Greek GDP[3].  It is worth noting that Germany has become increasingly skeptical of the viability of the Greek rescue, and not without reason: Greece keeps missing its targets, its debts remain very high and the above mentioned budget cuts are likely to stoke further political instability and push an ever larger share of the economy underground, reducing tax revenues and distorting further the economy.

Having forced private creditors to take a €106 billion loss without putting its debt on a realistic recovery path, Greece will ask the same from its public creditors next.  Despite the IMF insistence, the eurozone has so far adamantly refused, although chancellor Merkel recently acknowledged the inevitable, sort of.  Large scale privatizations continue to appear out of the question.

The problem is that, while another round of debt haircuts appears necessary, it is not sufficient to get Greece back on track.

Nowhere in Europe has the pain been greater than in Greece:  Nominal GDP dropped 7.6% from €232.9 billion in 2008 to an estimated €215.1 billion in 2011.  It is expected to drop close to 7% this year.  Labor costs have been greatly reduced and external accounts have adjusted considerably, although in large part because of low internal demand: the trade deficit[4] for the first nine months of 2012 was €10.1 billion compared to €18.6 billion in 2009 and €32.7 billion in 2008.

For the period 2009-2012, the Greek GDP will have fallen as much as that of Chile did in the early 1980s, yet the comparison stops there.  Chile carried out profound structural economic reforms during its depression years while Greece hasn’t.  Unless Greece invests massively to become more productive and to shift its output towards greater value added products, unless it shrinks its public sector, unless it designs a tax system that is efficient without being confiscatory, the above adjustments will prove to have been cyclical rather than structural.  So far, the situation is grim: for example, total investment as a percentage of GDP has gone from 23.7% in 2008 to 14.5% in 2011 and is likely to drop further this year.

At this stage, the odds of Greece remaining in the eurozone are slim although less dismal than they were last March.  To remain, it is necessary that Greece get a large debt reduction, but it is not sufficient.  Besides reforms it also needs the European Union, which absorbs over 62% of its exports, to recover too.

So far, it seems to me that Greece’s condition has gone from desperate to critical; perhaps there is room for further improvement.  The eurozone countries are starting to acknowledge that they can’t fully collect their loans to Greece.  They have yet to decide which avenue is best for them: granting a large haircut as the final boost to a recovering country and fellow eurozone member, or cutting their losses to a country exiting the eurozone.

I remain in the camp of the skeptics.



[1]  As per former ECB Board member J. Stark.
[2]  Essentially directed at the new bonds which Greece issued as part of its private debt restructuring.
[3]  Source: UBS.
[4]  Excluding oil products which are not included in the official time series.

Thursday, September 20, 2012

May 29, 2024


The police presence was heavy as usual, but the oppressive, volatile atmosphere that had cast a pall over the Champs Elysées, and indeed the whole city in previous weeks, had lifted.  Instead, an air of expectancy mixed with curiosity had gradually set among the assembled multitude.  But the police prefect was taking no chance, as dozens of armored transports and riot control vehicles were massed, out of sight, on the rue de Ponthieu and Avenue Kleber.

 “I wonder if he will bring his kids” wondered a thin man in a bright yellow Tshirt.  “Carla will not let him!” shot back his neighbor, “Besides, they don’t speak French so they wouldn’t understand what’s going on” added another.  “Well, is he coming or what, we’ve been waiting since four o’clock!” complained a neatly dressed middle aged woman.

HE had been waiting for an even longer time, twelve years to be exact.  He had lost the 2012 elections more than his adversary had won them.  The French had rejected an hyperactive President in favor of a calmer, blander alternative; they had turned their back on “a certain idea of France” and voted in favor of a more comfortable, traditional vision that had much in common with that of an ostrich in imminent danger.  In truth, HE had not helped his case: during most of his term, his unbound energy notwithstanding, he had rarely given a sense of what his governing priorities were or should be, and during the presidential campaign, he had shied away from focusing on the challenges and policy choices that faced the nation.

Hated by many, radioactive to his fellow UMP members, Nicolas Sarkozy had accepted a fellowship at the Hoover Institution of Stanford University.  Within a few years, he had added a teaching position at the university’s Political Science Department and become involved with Stanford’s famed Business School.  In 2018, the IPO of  Uwin, in which he had invested $200,000, made him the first billionaire ex-President.  He was half way through his traversée du desert[1].  Now a very wealthy man, and the symbol of the modern politician who reinvented himself successfully if unconventionally, Nicolas Sarkozy would spend another six years trying to reenter the French political scene. 

Far from the Californian shores, France was not doing so well.  Neither the new president nor the French felt like paring the budget.  Having promised his electors economic growth rather than public spending cuts, President Hollande found it difficult to backtrack, even when faced with a budget deficit bigger than expected.  Taxes on the rich were raised yet they brought in but a fraction of the needed revenues.  So fiscal policy was relaxed, deficit targets were postponed and pressure mounted on the ECB and Northern Europe to provide additional deficit financing.

Had France been isolated, it may have been forced to face the music, but it was not alone; Spain and Italy were in the same situation, having to push through austerity measures which were increasingly unpopular and politically explosive. 

On the other hand, Germany, already facing slowing economic growth and the fallout from China’s recession, was growing more and more concerned that its financial commitments vis-à-vis the eurozone were becoming so large as to be internally destabilizing.  Netherlands, Finland and Austria were on the same page, and in any case too small to shoulder a greater eurozone assistance program.

This all came to a head at the Antwerp conference of 2014.  The new Spanish prime minister, who had just spent two weeks battling with the regional governments of Catalonia, Andalusia and Murcia, announced that he was neither in a position to accept more outside supervision from the troika nor to pay the sovereign debt as scheduled.  His Italian homologue noted that his new coalition in Congress wished to revisit some of the reforms voted under the Mario Monti government and that, in any case, the Spanish crisis made it impossible for Italy to access the financial markets on sustainable terms.  France for its part had been under a three weeks general strike which had escaped the control of the two dominant unions, the CGT and the CFDT, and leftwing splinter parties under the leadership of Jean-Luc Mélenchon were calling for the nationalization of half of the companies in the CAC 40 index.  President Hollande had to decide which way to go.  In the end, he calculated that he couldn’t win over the strikers or the opposing political parties because they would never accept the necessary remedies which, in any case, he didn’t himself fully embrace.  He also felt that the country was far richer than generally acknowledged and could take care of its own financial problems if these were, at least partially, reduced.

On October 15, 2014 in Antwerp, Germany, Finland, Austria and the Netherlands formed the New Eurozone, anchored by the Euromark(€Mk).  Central banks’ balances with the ECB were to be settled via new 10 year ECB bonds.  Given the instant 30% appreciation of the €Mk vs. the €, Germany took an immediate mark-to-market loss of some €200 billion on its ECB credits.  On the other hand, it also showed a comparable gain on its outstanding sovereign debt for the opposite reason.  The top French, Italian and Spanish banks were nationalized.

In the months and year that followed this historical event, it became clear that Anwerp solved only in small part an economic problem, but was even less successful dealing with political challenges.

The German economy took a hit, but not as hard as some had feared.  The €Mk proved a serious headwind to exports and corporate profits, as German exporters cut their margins to the bone to preserve market share.  Imports by France, which represented 19% of total, plunged.  On the other hand, parts and other imports from France, Northern Italy and Spain rose.  Corporate efficiency campaigns went into high gear to mitigate the pricing headwind of a strong currency.  Endowed with a super strong €Mk, German companies accelerated new capital investments in Asia, Mexico and the US.  By the end of 2017, the German economy had regained it mojo, and the timely Chinese recovery proved an added bonus.

In France, the competitive boost gained from a weaker euro was transitory.  It weakened the case for deeper reforms.  It depressed consumption and therefore tax revenues.  Faced with a diminished purchasing power and depreciated savings, the population soon became restless and clamored for “a new deal”.  But faced with high borrowing costs, the government had limited resources.  So, in 2015, new taxes were levied on those who profited from the devaluation, mainly exporters and international firms.  Next, private savings were channeled to finance what amounted to general budgetary shortfalls.  As this was not sufficient, the government reached farther for new sources of funding.  In 2017, “Social Solidarity Financing Programs”, or PROFINSS, were started whereby public assets, services or institutions were used to collateralize new public debt issues.

The state of affairs was not very different in Italy and Spain.  In particular, social and political unrest had become pervasive in Spain where the central government was still faced with a volatile conflict with the regions.  For the first time in recent memory, Italy was faced with its own kind of regional strife, as Northern Italy was in open conflict with Rome.

With stagnant economies and restive populations, these three countries pressed the ECB to increase its emission of money, trying to compensate some of the adverse effects of this policy with export incentives and targeted compensatory schemes.  By 2020, most French salaries included indexation provisions and inflation had risen to 7% p.a.  At the same time, price controls had been expanded, so that the official consumer price index was widely viewed as understating inflation by several hundred points.

As we have seen the Antwerp conference and its aftermath had brought France little relief.  The 2017 presidential elections were hotly contested but the right lost handily, divided as it had always had been.  President Hollande also lost, to his minister Arnaud Montebourg.  The new president was viewed as more charismatic and “progressive” yet not as extreme as Mélenchon. Yet Mélenchon and his Left Party scored big at the legislative elections and assured their participation in the new government.  Also scoring big was the National Front of Marine Le Pen with the support of some refugees from the UMP.

By the time the 2022 elections came around, the world economy had mostly recovered from its slump of a decade before.  China was in the midst of its Domestic Frontier program aimed at accelerating the development of its Western provinces.  Mexico had become the latest emerging markets star and the leader of a revitalized Latin American free trade group which included Chile, Peru, Colombia and a reborn Venezuela whose oil production had reached 4 million barrels per day thanks to the historic opening of its energy sector to private companies.   The US too was on the mend, having flirted twice with disaster but finally built a block of moderates from both parties in the House.

Southern Europe lagged behind.  In France, the 2022 had brought a new president, former Socialist Party Secretary Martine Aubry in the same role of conciliator as that thrown upon Montebourg five years earlier.  The opposition was led by Marine Le Pen as the leader of the Union pour un Movement Républicain-UMR, the result of the fusion of the UMP and the National Front.

By then, the Socialists and the UMR parties had hardened their positions, as each firmly believed that it could impose its views, bloc the other and win over the support of the population thanks to massive demonstrations or other spectacular action.  Crime had become a major social issue and how to combat it was a key political battle ground; the CGT and CFDT unions backed the government while the police unions supported the more vigorous policies advocated by the opposition.  Over the next two years, the policy stalemate continued and pressure built.

In 2024, with little economic growth, continued capital flight and persistent inflation despite administrative price controls, the government took the fateful decision to nationalize what it called the Six Strategic Pillars of the economy: Electricité de France, France Telecom, Lafarge, Renault, Suez and Total.  The government had expected that this move would not be overly disruptive; after all, the Paris stock market had been in a state of torpor for years, all six stocks traded at already depressed levels and state intervention in their affairs was already pervasive.

Market and popular reaction was however wholly unexpected.  While many had not minded the state controlling prices and browbeating wealthy executives, they were now aghast that the attack was directed at their own property.  Also, while stock prices had been depressed for a long time, dividend yields were attractive as they approximated official inflation levels.  Finally, the nationalization raid had come out of the blue and nobody knew what else was in the offing.  On the far left, politicians were up in arm when the prime minister announced that compensation would be paid “based” on market prices; why should taxpayers money be used to reward those who had unjustly profited at the expense of the working class?  Institutional investors, for their part, wondered whether they should wait or just dump all their holdings.

On that day of May 21, 2024 the already depressed CAC 40 dropped by 27% before trading was halted.  International suppliers made it clear that they would suspend all non-essential dealing with the Six Pillars until further notice.  S&P, Moody’s and Fitch downgraded the Six’s credit ratings by five notches triggering sharp drops in their bond prices.  French sovereign and other top corporate bonds swooned in unison.

On the morning of the 22nd, the Paris Stock Exchange didn’t open for trading and a €4 billion OAT issue was cancelled.  By noon, when trading finally opened, the CAC 40 fell another 11% whereupon the exchange was closed for the day.  Sporadic runs by depositors on branches of BNP, Crédit Agricole and Société Générale were reported in Lille, Strasbourg and Grenoble.

By the 23rd, the UMR had called on the government to explain its ill advised nationalization in Congress, with supporters and detractors engaging in shooting matches and government members occasionally ducking for cover as projectiles of various shape and weight flew across the Chamber.  Outside, civilians, union members, and employees of the Six were picketing, milling around and waiting for something to happen.

On the 26th, two things became crystal clear: (1) the government was going to fall, and (2) the UMR had zero chance to replace it.

And so, on the 29th of May, 2024, at approximately 6 pm, Nicolas Sarkozy, former president (2007-2012), former fellow of the Hoover Institution, venture capitalist extraordinaire, walked up the length of the Champs Elysées, accompanied by his wife Carla and his two daughters, and by the clamor of half a million French.  His hair was grey and his cheeks were rounder, but years of surfing in California had helped him stay in shape, and he effortlessly glided up the famed avenue. 

The government had resigned; President Aubry had asked Nicolas Sarkozy to form a new one.  She had also agreed to resign within three months so that new elections could be called.  Already, brand new banners, white and blue background with “France Avenir” in bold red letters, were fluttering in the breeze, portends of campaign soon to be launched.

The above is just an exercise in political fiction, although it attempts to find a realistic base in history and economic realities.  But it is only that.  Alternative scenario could have been proposed which would have a chance of happening.  The point of this fable is not to guess what the future will be like.  It is to illustrate as vividly as possible the fact that the latest debt and European crises have had severe economic consequences, yet relatively mild political ones. 

In our view, the next few years are likely to bring about political upheaval on a scale comparable with the economic upheaval we have been through so far.



[1]  Literally, crossing of the desert.